NBU and Inflation Targeting: Monetary Policy Rules for the Road Ahead
By Alex Nikolsko-Rzhevskyy (Lehigh University, USA)
On July 3, 2014, in her speech at the
conference titled “Ukraine’s European Vector: Impact on Business,” the National
Bank of Ukraine’s (NBU) newly appointed governor, Valeriia Gontareva (Valeriya
Hontaryeva in another transcription), underscored her commitment to targeting inflation. The current end-of-year inflation
rate currently anticipated nearly
19% will likely prompt an aggressive tightening
of monetary policy, thereby lowering inflation to more acceptable levels with
the intent to then keep it under control. A reasonable inflation target could perhaps
be in the vicinity of 4%, which though exceeding the more common long-term inflation
targets of 2.0-2.5% exhibit by developed economies such as the U.S. and Canada,
is nevertheless in the ballpark of peer and aspiring developing countries such
as Poland and Hungary. As such, what exactly should the Ukrainian public and its
economy expect to happen in the middle to long run? Putting yet-unresolved structural
issues aside
and assuming that immediate threats, including aggressive speculative attacks on the hryvnia, are defused, let us discuss the mechanics of the process of
reducing inflation and various ways to mitigate the painful transition, using past
international experiences as examples.
While there are many tools available for conducting
monetary policy -- including setting reserve requirements, extending discount
loans to commercial banks, paying interest on reserves, as well as several less
conventional methods -- the
most common tool used in normal circumstances by most central banks is open
market operations, which vary the supply of available reserves and thus affect
their implicit price: the interbank rate. Tightening policy usually involves the
aggressive sale of bonds by the central bank, which results in upward movements
of short-term interest rates. Economic theory suggests that such an increase
has an adverse effect on aggregate demand, sending the country into a recession
in the short run, primarily by discouraging planned investment. A well-known
example of such an effect is Paul Volker’s disinflation in
the U.S. during 1980-1986. By conducting monetary tightening, though the Fed
was able to reduce inflation from 13.5% down to 1.9%, it came at the cost of reduced
production and a mid-transition rise in unemployment from 7.1% to 9.7%. Should
we expect a similar outcome in Ukraine? The answer is both yes and no. While
the direction of the impact will also be negative, its magnitude could actually
be greater. For this, the central bank’s credibility and public’s expectations
about inflation are crucial concerns.
Public disbelief in a central bank’s ability or
desire to control inflation builds up inflationary pressure, which multiplies
the negative effects of monetary policy tightening on GDP and exacerbates a
recession. This mechanism works by bringing about upward adjustments in new long-term
wage contracts, which decreases aggregate supply as the expected inflation
increases. These increased expectations will hurt the economy regardless of the
true NBU intentions and the sincerity of Ms. Gontareva’s desire to control
inflation, as long as the public has reasons to question their motives. Unfortunately,
for Ukraine, the rational public has every reason not to trust the NBU’s claims
to actively combat inflation. While several factors could be involved, the most
important one are corruption and (at least perceived) close ties between the NBU and the Ukrainian
government.
In Ukraine, since the NBU Council members are
appointed (and can be fired) by the president of Ukraine and the Verkhovna
Rada, the central bank can hardly be considered to be independent. Political
dependency and corruption typically result in so-called inflationary bias by
causing monetary policymakers exercise discretion, lower the rates, and exploit
the short-run tradeoff between inflation and employment, thus increasing the chances that their patrons are reelected.
Such expansionary policy, however, eventually raises workers’ and firms’
expectations about inflation, which drives up both wages and prices and results
in permanently higher inflation without any increase in output. Indeed, data show that countries with less independent central banks
face higher inflation rates. In today’s Ukraine, we can
expect political pressure to be especially strong given that planned monetary
policy tightening is expected to further deteriorate already less-than-stellar economic conditions.
Can anything be done to convince
the public that the NBU will honor its promise to bring down and control
inflation, thus anchoring or even decreasing inflationary pressure, while preventing
self-fulfilling prophesies from depraving the economy? Perhaps. Since it is
impossible to neither completely eliminate the established culture of
corruption nor easily change the Ukrainian Constitution, one option is to reduce
the influence of the human factor. The belief that policymakers can be
time-inconsistent emerges alongside their ability to exercise discretion. Had it instead been replaced
with rules, the problem would have vanished.
What are rules? Policy rules are
binding plans that specify how policy will respond (or not respond) to
particular data such as unemployment and inflation. This strategy is the
opposite to the current NBU strategy -- discretion, applied when policymakers make
no commitment to future actions, but instead make decisions according to what
they believe to be best for the situation in that moment. One of the most famous and successful rules is the Taylor rule,
according to which central banks adjust their target interbank rate in response
to deviations of the inflation rate from the target and output from the trend.
It is crucial that the cumulative inflation response coefficient is above one
so that when there is an inflation shock, the nominal interest rate goes up more
than one to one with inflation, thereby raising the real interest rate. The
commonly agreed size of the coefficient is 1.5, and it appears to work well for
many different economies. The output gap coefficient is more controversial,
but the suggested value typically falls between 0.5 and 1.0.
The chief advantage of using rules instead
of discretion is the elimination of the time-inconsistency problem -- if
policymakers are bound by a strict plan, then it will be difficult for them to
extend political favors. Moreover, rules can decrease the probability of a policy mistake and are generally found to perform better than discretion
in terms of economic outcomes. The benefits of rules should be especially
pronounced in corrupt economies with less independent central banks, and
Ukraine at the present time definitely falls into that category.
Of course, for rules to work, the
Verkhovna Rada would have to legislate the NBU’s commitment to them, thus
penalizing deviations; otherwise, using rules will not be different from exercising
discretion. Rules themselves are not without drawbacks: they are rigid and
might ignore useful information such as expert opinion. Hence, infrequent
deviations from or changes to the optimal policy rule are warranted at times, for
instance, due to structural changes in the economy. The legislation therefore
needs to be flexible enough to allow the exercise of limited discretion in the
time of need, while being strict enough to make the central bank honor the commitment.
A good starting point could be the
U.S. Federal Reserve Accountability and Transparency Act of 2014. Among other things, this recently-proposed legislation requires
the Fed to adopt a Directive Policy Rule. This rule would be chosen by the Federal
Open Market Committee and would describe how the federal funds rate would
respond to a change in the intermediate policy variables, presumably inflation
and one or more measures of real economic activity such as the output gap, the
unemployment rate, and real GDP growth. If the Fed deviated from its rule, the
Chair of the Fed would be required to testify before the appropriate
congressional committees as to why it is not in compliance. While it might seem
that adopting similar legislation could further reduce the NBU’s independence, it
would in fact it make its actions more transparent and accountable, thereby making
it more difficult for interest groups to manipulate its decisions.
Notice that nothing in the proposed
legislation restricts the form of the Directive Rule. Moreover, it does not even
specify whether it should be a simple linear formula, such as the Taylor rule,
or a set of agreed-upon instructions for how to react to a particular economic
development -- the choice is completely up to bank officials. Obeying any reasonable rule would prevent the
NBU from taking populist measures. And if the central bank were to deviate, it
would improve transparency for the Governor to explain why.
While the NBU’s immediate goals
will likely focus on speculative attacks and the ongoing war in eastern Ukraine,
the Council should use this time to build up their reputation by consistently
making promises and then delivering on them. This will help to establish
credibility. To maintain credibility in the future, switching to a rules-based
policy might be the solution.
I think Ukraine is unfortunately too open economy with extremely high dependency on global commodity price to allow NBU to use rules and simple monetary policies. Neither inflation targeting nor having rules on how-to-adjust target interbank rates would not work in the economy, where 1) Exports in half of GDP and half of exports comprises of commodities, 2) 44% of corporate debt is denominated in foreign currency.
ReplyDeleteAnd here is once again the argument why inflation targeting would not work in Ukraine: 20% drop in metal and agriculture prices (which could easily happen) would cause current account gap of 5% of GDP but only 3-4pp deflation. If NBU follows inflation targeting it would devaluate hryvnya by no more than 6-8% to adjust inflation to the trend. This would leave current account unbalanced given that elasticity of import to devaluation is much less <1.
Before we get to have our economy less dependent on commodity export we would not be able to follow inflation targeting. Or any other strict rules which would limit national bank’s flexibility.
While the council of the NBU is both installed and fired by the president and parliament, the true power is not in the council but in the board, which is responsible for day-to-day action. And where we have a problem not with legislation but with its execution. Say in late 2002, in order to ‘free’ the seat of the NBU governor for Tihipko (whose faction in return supported Yanukovych for the PM), then-governor Stelmakh was pressed to leave the seat voluntarily because he cannot be fired. Similarly in 2005 Tihipko had to leave the seat and so on. As long as this seat is a part of political bargaining process, the problem persists.
ReplyDeleteI may be wrong, for a quick google search hasn’t supplied me with data, but formally the NBU ranking in Cukierman’s central bank independence index is in par with many central banks of CEE, so while the law can be improved, it is not that bad if it was adhered to.
Taylor rule is an option, but remember that when the decision is taken, the level of GDP is not known, so an estimate is used, with is then compared with another estimate, namely potential GDP. Thus there can be notable error margin and if the NBU is the one, which supplies both estimates, it can be biased.
That is interesting approach to oblige the central bank to use the strict rules approved in advance. But I doubt that such approach could be used in the developing country with small open economy like Ukraine (at least I have never met something similar except of MP rules in the published models). Usually such countries do not follow the "full-fledged" inflation targeting, but rather "flexible" one. Except of inflation (and output volatility) targets external sustainability and financial stability are the important goal of the central banks in such countries. I suppose Ukraine is not the exception here. I agree that the National Bank of Ukraine should follow some monetary policy rule in general, but most likely Ukrainian economy will be hit by severe macroeconomic shocks which will require the "flexible" reaction from authorities. However, I agree with the overall suggestion of author that the autonomy and independence of the NBU from the Government should be raised in order to achieve the credibility for its monetary policy. It’s a crucial issue for the success of the new monetary regime of inflation targeting.
ReplyDelete